Feeds:
Posts
Comments

Archive for May, 2007

Surabaya – Memoire

泗水心得与感想

五月十七日

天已亮,我看我手机闹钟还没到我该要起床时间,却心里觉得不安,真担心我起不来然后没时间赶到机场。知道时间还早,我就先冲个凉,准备好好衣服与开始打包行李。哦对,昨天到今天我似乎不能决定要带较大的箱子或者是要带小包包回。本来有些我已放好衣服在大箱子,然后我突然间就下了决定别带那么大又麻烦的大包,小型的包包就好,想想在家里能穿一件衣服两三次也好。我镌带了许多衣服和生活用品包括我手机充电器还有自己的小毛巾。

身上穿的衣服我自己觉得挺有帅气。哈哈。还带着领带和夹克到处逛呢。嘿嘿。我就搭捷运到机场。到了机场我看时间还真早,便找个地方来坐坐。我选了汉堡王的学生套餐当我的早餐,然后没想到我刚买的米咯饮料不小心倒在地上了。唉,真倒霉的一天。还好没沾到我衣服。发现四周的人都在看着我,我就TMD装酷不可. 哈哈.. 我上了飞机之后不知不觉地睡着了。到了泗水机场我就等着我姐姐来接我,果然等了十五分钟人没出现我就自己想办法找个电话亭打个电话给我姐。问她怎么没来接我时,她说她已派一位司机在机场来接我,我就问那位司机的电话号码咯。碰见了司机我就跟他聊了许多有关泗水的大概路怎走。

我不好意思地借他的手机发个短信给我朋友,到了地点我就下车看到我父和全家人。这时候我身体状况还ok,没想到我第二天就病倒了。我姐夫的旧房挺大的,有游泳池,反正比我家好像大一两倍似的。只不过最近这间房没人住,所以暂时给我全家人住到拜六为止。傍晚时我和全家人拜访到姐夫家共享晚餐。他家离咱们那里不远,位于较大的路旁,里面空间超级大噎。吃完饭后我和我爸聊了一下有关这间屋子的真正价值在哪儿,也就是屋子地面的大理石切得较大大个代表真正的价值。还有里面的图画也蛮特别,还有二楼他们那里也有游泳池,我到周围到处看了之后就觉得羡慕不已。只不过有个缺点所在就是难以打扫。天花板的高度一般人家的梯子也爬不到啊。还需要雇许多用人才能把这种房子维持清洁。吃完饭咱们就回去休息。

五月十八日

没想到隔天我身体就得病,显然被我妈传染到了。喉咙觉得很不舒服,吞下口水时也疼痛。体内上风而发烧,想动也动不了,可能昨晚空调开得太大了所以就这样倒下咯。本来我和我朋友约好了时间今天要见面,因为我生病而不能去。那只好想办法另外找时间见个面咯。然后下午呢,我妈叫我到我亲戚家那里看病,他是个满有名的耳鼻喉外科医生,诊我了之后我妈就叫我来打一针,医生也勉强我打个针,他说打完针然后服药,明天就会痊愈。就这样,晚上我爸帮我买了鸡粥吃,还好我食欲还在。吃完我头觉得很晕,整晚身体觉得疼痛,盖了棉被,冷气也已经关掉了,体内还是一样觉得很冷还会发抖呢。不过最后我还是有办法睡觉(服了药之原因吧)。

五月十九日

还好昨天有看病并且打了针,我早上起床时觉得有百分之八十已康复。我喉咙觉得舒缓了下来,起了床之后我妈赶紧叫我快点冲凉吃早餐然后准备搬到附近的旅馆去。今天轮到我姐夫从雅加达的亲戚来住这里。我全家人住在附近的三星级的旅馆,叫somerset, 服务不错,环境良好。到了那里天已晚,我因身体觉得还未适而选择呆在旅馆看电视。我哥和他的未婚妻出去吃晚餐顺便帮买个晚餐吃。我等到晚上九点饭才到。吃完饭我哥叫我马上上床就睡。唉。吃完肚子还很饱呢。我哥就打电话给服务人员叫他明天帮我们五点起床。

五月廿日

五点早上起床准备要出发到sheraton旅馆拜茶,洗完澡过后咱们俩就到二楼和叔叔同桌享用早餐。他就跟大家暗示说要自己开创做生意才是个较好选择。我心理想每个人也都想要自己当个老板而却无法实现,不但没有机会与资本,可能不是每个人都有本事做,不是每个人都会有那种出人头地的心态之原因罢了。我自己也想要自己做生意,可是这点需要能干,勇气与奋斗。讲到这一点我回忆到我叔叔的办公室里有挂着类似座右铭曰:人的一生,全靠奋斗。唯有奋斗,才能成功。这点我非常同意。我叔叔接着问我哥哥最近的情况,他也知我哥哥要出国到澳洲那里讨经验,并且问他接下来的计划。哈哈。他就难以回答。依我所知,他的未婚妻现在在某一个私立的银行上班,他明年就准备要结婚,结婚这点对我来说是生活安定下来的开始。

吃完早餐我们就去我姐姐那里拜茶咯。我见到远方的亲戚,他们不能不觉得很希奇,看我已不像以前矮小又调皮,现在已成熟多咯哈哈。拜完茶了之后咱们就回到旅馆休息四五个小时,然后过去Pakuwon Imperial Country Club 那里做彩排。我原本想邀请我两位朋友参加只不过我姐姐怕不够位,所以没办法咯。彩排并没有按时计划而举行,有一些来宾已到了现场。傍晚七点正式开始,差不多五小时节目里有三位明星来主持。花了多少费用我难以想象,反正很多就是了。可是我真的是以我姐姐感到为荣。节目搞到一个段落之后呢,为了保护那些金银财宝,装饰那些和全家人的安全,我妈也有请了警方保送安排。哦对,本来我想和那些主持人拍个照当作纪念,不过他下台时已不知踪影,听说他赶到飞机场要出国似的。唉,太迟了。唉真可惜。

五月廿一日

这天我在旅馆里呆着看电视,看哪种增加见闻频道,哦对,我试着打个电话给我朋友,嘉玲和mira,可是他们俩因上班而不能够去。晚上我全家人和亲戚吃晚餐,便聊了最近的情况如何什么的。

五月廿二日

也就是我父母全家回雅加达的一天,我原本打算在开龙哥哥那里住一晚,想想我姐夫家离机场不会比开龙哥哥远,所以我就说好在我姐夫那里过夜。这天我已约好我两位朋友在某一个泗水最大的娱乐场所见个面。我在哪儿等了超久,我抵达哪里是下午两点,逛了逛没什么好看,上下电梯到处逛,然后就想利用时间去看蜘蛛侠第三部曲。门票花我差不多三块钱新币不到,真TMD便宜。然后我买了点心,署片和可乐花了跟门票差不多一样的价钱。真TMD贵。看完了之后刚好傍晚七点。

在某个咖啡店地点约好了之后呢,嘉玲带他的老公一起,而mira独自一个人来的。咱们四个人在楼下的蛮不错的X.O中国类似的餐厅吃晚餐,讲了很多有关朋友们的消息与最近发展,嘉玲他还有他的老公现在在泗水的某一个地方开了杂货店。专门卖鸡蛋之类的。然后mira呢,他在某一个学校当补习老师。两位气色都很不错。生活过得挺好的。而我呢,还在求学,还要跟老爸要钱,真令人可耻不已。唉。咱们聊满久,我就假装上个厕所,哦对,上厕所也要给钱的。真搞笑呢。接下来我就自愿地请客他们咯。要走之前我就跟他们说了我已经付了,谢他们要跟我见面之意。接下来咱们四个就找个地方来拍照,当作纪念类似的。我回家时已经满晚咯。我就跟他们说谢谢能送我到家。嘉玲家离我姐夫家满近的。我那天晚上就不能够睡好,在别人床睡觉觉得不舒服呢。

五月廿三日

我早上差不多八点起床,看那透明的窗户我就怕他们发现我还在睡觉的模式,我就立刻起床而后洗个澡。吃了早餐之后我就会觉得不好意思,很尴尬,早知道我去开龙哥哥的家,心情就会较好些。真没想到今天我对我姐夫的母亲而感到令人心里有点不适的感觉。唉。真难受。还好司机已经在门外等我,虽然我飞机是六点起飞的,可是我下午一点就已经离开我姐夫家了。在机场等了差不多五个钟头多,真无聊。飞机场里面也没什么地方好逛,就像那种生活在很偏僻的地方似的。

从泗水上飞机到新加坡的人数满多。我飞机本来是四点起飞的,却被拖延到六点正式起飞。飞机上有东西吃,可是很难吃。唉。到了新加坡机场时,时间显示已经快要晚上十点了。我就搭捷运回家。到家了之后我马上洗个澡,准备明天复习课程的计划。

泗水心得与感想由此搞一个段落。

Read Full Post »

Markus lynne

Markus Lynne – Power politics and MIS implementation

People determined

The factors may be common to all people or to one particular group. Some examples are people may resist all change, or analytical people may accept the system while intuitive people may not. People have there own distinct personality types. As seen by Benbasat and Taylor, each person has their own distinctive cognitive traits. Depending upon their human processing system, they may find the system difficult to understand. Thus they would resist change. Each person also have their own personal experiences and biases. Depending on if they had input into the system and who the system was built for, they may be biased towards the system being implemented. Goodwin also states that people must understand the system, it’s functions, and how to use it, or they may become frustrated. Designing a system requires understanding the user, their levels of expertise, the amount of use, and how their needs will change.

System determined

We saw before that the type of person may resist the application or the system, whether good or bad. This time we disregard the type of person and focus on the system. People will not use the system or use it infrequently if the system or application is bad. For example, this very application, PowerPoint, is very annoying with it’s pop ups and auto formats. People may find it annoying to use the web at another persons because it is not fast enough. If a system is poorly designed, then people will resist using it. If the interface is hard to follow and not easy to read and navigate, then they will not use it. Goodwin wanted functionality as well as usability. Otherwise, people would find it annoying. Different people have different requirements, each of which must be accommodated by a well designed system.

Interaction Theory

This theory is not the same as believing in the past two theories at the same time. Systems that centralize control over data, systems that alter the balance of power within the company, and resistance to the technical design aspects of the system with the social sub context implied. This explanation does not take into account the system or the person using it, just the interaction between the two. This theory has several variations, two of which are sociotechnical and political. Sociotechnical focuses the distribution of labor and work. Political has to do with power and the shift in power. Certain people will resist change because the new system will shift the power away from them.

Read Full Post »

IS Articles :D

Keen –
Counter Implementation (how to oppose a decided change without showing your face:
1. lay low
2. rely on inertia
3. keep things complex, hard to coordinate, and vaguely defined.
4. minimize the legitimacy and influence of the change agent.
5. exploit the lack of knowledge of the change agent.

Counter counter implementation (how to cope with counter implementation)
1. make sure you have a contract for change.
2. seek out resistance; treat it as a signal to be responded to.
3. rely on face to face contact.
4. become an insider; work hard to build personal credibility.
5. co-opt users early.

Keywords
Politics and packaged software.

1. Introduction

A significant number of organisations operating in diverse business sectors are
adopting packaged software. That is, software which is generally sold as a tradable
product via a vendor, distributor or store (Sawyer, 2000). In particular, packages such
as those to support Customer Relationship Management (CRM) are becoming very
popular in supporting organisational strategies (Light, 2001b). Indeed, there is a
growing tradition of research into packaged software that has recently been fuelled by
the take up of applications such as those for Enterprise Resource Planning. Packaged
software research has focussed upon issues associated with selection (Chau, 1994;
Chau, 1995), implementation (Ciborra and Failla, 2000; Markus et al., 2000), usage
(Light, 2001a) and packaged software as a product (Keil and Carmel, 1995; Sawyer,
2001). However, there remains a dearth of attention in respect of the political aspects
of packaged software. It is with this backdrop that the author presents a case study
that is used to illustrate a range of issues associated with the politics of packaged
software implementation.
The next section of the paper provides an overview of the political issues in
information systems and considers how such issues are reported upon in the literature.
This is followed by the research methodology leading to the presentation and analysis
of the case study. The empirical data is used as a basis for an analysis of the reported
thinking in the literature in an attempt to identify similarities and disparities between
the two. This leads into the conclusions of the study and recommendations for further
research.
Christopher Bull Politics in Packaged Software Implementation

2. Political Issues in Information Systems

There are some who dismiss the political significance of information systems
(Gouldner, 1976). Those subscribing to the functionalist approach believe that issues
in the development of information systems are based on technical, rather than sociopolitical
issues. Therefore information systems development is perceived to be a
singularly rational or a politically neutral process. Functionalist theory has been
heavily criticised by many for being naïve (Knights and Murray, 1994) or inaccurate
(Markus, 1983).
The politics of information systems involves a range of important and complex issues
and has evolved from the literature on the relationship between information and
power which has a fairly long tradition (Wilensky, 1967), (Pettigrew, 1972) and
(Greenberger et al., 1976). Studies continue to highlight the link between access or
control of information and the preservation or advancing of organisational power and
influence (Standing and Standing, 1998). Some studies have also highlighted that
naïve actors in political situations can be seriously disadvantaged (Franz and Robey,
1984). Some studies have been cautious about an automatic link between information
and power, whilst Robert McNamara’s success (Ford, US Government and World
Bank) was attributed to being an effective user of information, Archie McCardell
(Xerox) successful career was considered not to be related (Pfeffer, 1992).
The evidence that information systems are a political and technical process is
considerable (Sillince and Mouakket, 1998). A recurring theme is that information
systems have a political dimension because of their potential to influence
organisational change in respect of issues such as organisational relationships,
patterns of communication, influence, authority and control (Keen, 1981). In
addition, an early study of organisational IT expenditure concluded that it involved
many disputes often resulting in irreconcilable differences between actors (Pettigrew,
1973). Other studies have highlighted that information systems have the potential to
become a political and tactical battleground where individuals or groups perceive
such processes as non-rational or against their interests, thus they seek to counter or
undermine projects by trying to divert resources or deflect its goals (Bardach, 1977;
Keen, 1981).
There are divergent political ideologies relating to information systems. One of the
most analysed areas could be termed as the negative theory of information systems
politics. The negative ethos is associated with many strands of oppositional political
theory and often characterised by counter-resistance. Actors are said to oppose and
counter information systems implementations if they perceive them to result in
domination (Morgan, 1997) or they increase surveillance (Zuboff, 1989). The issue of
counter-implementation is classically developed by the three theories of resistance:
people-determined, system-determined and the interaction theory (Markus, 1983).
People-determined theory relates to the propensity of information systems to enable
organisational change and of human nature to fear or resist change. Systemdetermined
theory of resistance occurs when information systems are opposed
because they are perceived to be deficient or non ergonomic. The interaction theory of
resistance occurs where systems fundamentally change cultural norms, roles or the
balance of power within an organisation i.e. a centralised system in a de-centralised
structure. The interaction theory of resistance has been endorsed by many additional
studies. (Broadbent et al., 1991) demonstrated that resistance resulted in project
failure due to non-compliance, delay tactics and the seeking of organisational
alliances to derail the will of the sponsor. (Myers and Young, 1997) highlighted how
Christopher Bull Politics in Packaged Software Implementation
the resistance theory successfully defeated attempts to use information systems as
steering mechanism for imposing the political will of one group (Department of
Health) onto another (health care employees).
Marxist theory is often extended to view information systems as a conflicting political
arena contested by the existence of distinct classes (e.g. senior management, middle
management, IT professionals and system users) and the inequalities of power and
influence between such groups. Case study research of two CADCAM system
implementations appears to support and undermine Marxist theory (Tantoush and
Clegg, 2001). Both cases can be perceived as groups exerting power over others to
achieve their aims. The first case concludes that whilst senior managers lacked
technical expertise in the project they achieved their aims by dividing and isolating
dissenters e.g. engineers. In the second case, the conclusion is that disparate groups
worked together fairly cohesively because of a shared perception to unite to counter a
greater threat e.g. an external actor. So whilst case study evidence supports elements
of Marxist theory they also reveal that such behaviour is not inevitable or the only
cause of conflict. Similarly whilst gender issues and conflict continue to generate
great interest (Adam, 2002) and the dominance of masculinity can be an important
factor in the politics of information systems (Knights and Murray, 1994) many have
criticised such theories as mono causal or too deterministic (Hekman, 1990).
The positive ethos could be viewed as fairly accommodating to political activity in
information systems because of the value of open dialogue in order to effectively
establish and interpret the true nature of contentious or problematic issues. Another
strand of the positive ethos is in the use of information systems to empower or
emancipate human-organisational activities. The positive theory has been relatively
neglected, however, could be emerging through the significance placed within the
theory of knowledge management and the desire to empower individuals or groups
with greater access to knowledge for effective dissemination (Marshall and Brady,
2001) and (Alavi and Leidner, 2001). The neutral ethos supports the view that
political issues in information systems are inevitable and therefore need to be
addressed; however, it is critical of the positive and negative theories because of their
attempts to predetermine such complexities. Finally, the academic literature relating
to the issues associated with political apathy in information systems is relatively
scarce, despite the increased incidents of such phenomena in other political
environments.
Classifying political theories is problematic and it is inevitable that many can be
criticised for their deterministic tendencies or countered by alternative perspectives
and findings. However, for (Markus, 1983) and (Keen, 1981), the real value and
purpose of examining the politics of information systems is to broaden our
understanding of political issues in order to try and attempt to predict or prevent
resistance. This is a theme increasingly endorsed by the increasing focus and attention
in the literature relating to the information systems project management. Project
management is increasingly being perceived as an intensely political arena and
significant attention is now being devoted in attempt to develop strategic thinking in
relation to improving negotiation techniques (Pinto, 1996).

Read Full Post »

Labour Process THeory..

1
The Labour Process: Still Stuck? Still a Perspective? Still Useful?
by: Jim Kitay
Many researchers who are interested in critical perspectives on work and organizations were
influenced by the labour process debates. I first encountered Braverman’s work in 1980, when a
reading group of which I was a member spent several weeks studying Labor and Monopoly Capital.
As my main interest at that time was in the state rather than the workplace, other labour process
writings came to my attention only slowly, and it was not until the late 1980s that I became aware of
the full nature and extent of the literature.
By that time the shortcomings of the early labour process approach had been identified. John Storey,
an important contributor to the early debates (Storey 1983) had already announced that “It is perhaps
not an exaggeration to claim that the labour process bandwagon has run into the sand” (Storey 1985,
194), and he questioned whether its problems could be resolved.
If the bandwagon was stuck in the sand, there have been a number of attempts to extricate it. The main
vehicle for returning it to the road – I do not wish to belabour the metaphor – was the annual UMISTAston
Labour Process Conference in the UK. With a mix of regular and occasional participants, these
conferences yielded a steady output of published work from the mid 1980s onwards. However, is it
still appropriate to speak of a labour process perspective? And what contribution has this work made
to our understanding of work and organizations?
If there ever was a unified labour process perspective, it is questionable whether a cohesive theory can
still be identified. A number of processes have been at work, which might be termed dissolution,
fragmentation, assimilation and cooptation. After a brief introduction to some of the main early
contributions to labour process theory, these four processes will be outlined.
Much of the early work on labour process theory was written within a broad Marxist framework.
Braverman (1974) played a crucial role in resurrecting this neglected aspect of Marx’s work, and three
of the key texts in second wave labour process theory – Burawoy (1979), Richard Edwards (1979) and
Friedman (1977) – were written from a Marxist perspective.
Braverman’s was the seminal contribution to the contemporary labour process debates. His influence
on the study of work coincided with an outpouring of radical scholarship across a range of fields, and
Braverman’s study is linked with this literature, particularly general political economy and the study
of class. Indeed, although his analysis begins in the workplace, later chapters include discussions of
class structure, the spread of market relations and the role of the state.
The focus of Braverman’s book is the processes allegedly leading to the degradation of work,
particularly scientific management as espoused by Frederick Taylor. Scientific management,
according to Braverman, is the manifestation of the logic of capitalism in the monopoly era. It is “a
theory which is nothing less than the explicit verbalization of the capitalist mode of production” (1974,
86), whose “fundamental teachings have become the bedrock of all work design”. In Braverman’s
view, other schools of management thought such as human relations provide little more than a rhetoric
for “the maintenance crew for the human machinery” (1974, 87).
Several themes can be found in Braverman’s writing, which as Littler (1990) notes, underlie the main
directions of the labour process debates. The first theme, which drew the most attention at the outset,
was the argument that capitalism contains a logic of deskilling manifested in Taylorism. This involved
a twofold process of job fragmentation and the progressive separation of conception from execution in
the process of production. Braverman sketched a transition from production dominated by the
scientific knowledge and craft skills of workers to a situation in which management exercises full
control over the knowledge and design of the production process. Each step of the labour process
2
would be broken down into its simplest elements, management would determine the most efficient
method of performing the task and provide detailed instructions which workers would follow
unquestioningly. Taylor anticipated considerable increases in productivity through the simplification
of production into specialized tasks, as well as allowing management to combat the “systematic
soldiering” that he believed accompanied workers’ control. The result, Braverman argued, would be a
dynamic of deskilling, with workers performing increasingly routine, fragmented tasks without
understanding the principles underlying the production process.
The second theme was control. Braverman (1974, 68) considered control to be “the central concept of
all management systems”. It is “essential for the capitalist that control over the labor process pass from
the hands of the worker into his own” (1974, 58), and Braverman is usually understood to view control
over labour as the fundamental problem of management. Thus Taylorism was not simply a system of
job design, but of control over alienated labour (1974, 90). Braverman was particularly interested in
the use of technology to transfer control over the labour process from workers to management (eg
1974, 194).
Finally, Braverman explored the implications of scientific management for class structure, leading to
an exploration of labour markets. His analysis is based on traditional Marxist categories of a reserve
army of labour, productive and unproductive labour, and class fractions. His general theme was a
secular trend of proletarianization, with labour being released from industries which were subject to
mechanization and clustering in industries less amenable to technological advances, particularly
clerical, sales and service work. This would result in a polarization of wage levels in the working
class, with higher paid men in the stagnant or declining industries subject to mechanization, and lower
paid women in industrialized countries and workers in less developed countries concentrated in the
rapidly growing labour intensive industries.
Several reformulations of labour process theory from a Marxist perspective soon followed in the
“second wave” of analysis. The primary focus of such writers as Friedman, Richard Edwards and
Burawoy was the question of control. Braverman’s belief that scientific management was the form of
control in capitalism was criticised as simplistic. Friedman (1977) agreed that employees could be
subject to forms of “direct control” such as Taylorism, but argued that there were limitations to direct
control that could be partially counteracted by introducing policies of “responsible autonomy” for
sections of the workforce. This was not simply a facade to cover Taylorist practices, which was
Braverman’s view of job re-design approaches, but rather “attempts to harness the adaptability of
labour power by giving workers leeway and encouraging them to adapt to changing situations in a
manner beneficial to the firm” (1977, 78). Richard Edwards (1979) posited a secular trend in control
strategies from the “simple control” characteristic of small workplaces to “technical control” in which
management sought to use the control capabilities of machinery and technological innovations such as
assembly lines, to the “bureaucratic control” found in the long career ladders and elaborate rule books
of large corporations.
It was often asserted that Braverman had neglected the Marxist tenet that alienated labour inherently
resists management. Friedman and Richard Edwards, however, argued that the changing forms of
control they identified arose from conflict between management and labour. This “control-resistance”
model remained popular amongst radical commentators for some time (see eg Probert 1989), but in
another major “second wave” contribution Burawoy (1979) noted that basing labour process analysis
on such conflictual foundations could not account for the prevalence of cooperation in most
workplaces much of the time. Consent, Burawoy argued, arises from the organization of activities in
workplaces in such a way that workers perceive themselves as having choices. “It is participation in
choosing that generates consent.” (1979, 27) From this, Burawoy developed his well known analysis
of “games”, activities which deflect workers’ attention away from the expropriation of surplus value
by employers, towards activities designed to “beat” the employer in matters such as incentive
payments or otherwise organize workplace activities in a manner more favourable to employees. This
argument suggests that the opportunity to gain small victories masks the fundamental disadvantage of
workers in the capitalist mode of production.
3
With this brief introduction to some of the key early writings on the labour process, we can note, first,
how a process of dissolution quickly commenced. The first stage of dissolution involved a critique of
the initial Marxist framework of labour process theory, particularly Braverman’s work, by sympathetic
non-Marxist writers. More recently, a post-structuralist or Foucauldian influence has entered the
debate, presenting itself as a significant departure from both Marxism and radical political economy or
sociology.
Avowedly Marxist writers such as Friedman, Richard Edwards and Burawoy shared much in common
with others who joined in the early debates. For example, in another major contribution to second
wave labour process theory, Littler (1982) retained the radical orientation of Marxism but based his
work equally on the more critical aspects of Weberian theory. In addition to a critique of arguments on
scientific management, Littler also sought to link labour process arguments on control with the
Weberian concepts of bureaucracy and legitimation. He concluded that a more complex approach was
needed in which the labour process was conceptualized as operating on three levels – job design, the
structure of control and the employment relationship. These levels have a degree of independence, and
allow for mixed strategies to be employed. While Littler did not develop an extended theory of
ideology, his use of Weberian constructs led to an analysis of subjectivity at work which potentially
covered a wider range of workplace actions than Burawoy’s discussion of consent and games.
Similarly, in an article which became a basic reference in the radical literature on labour markets,
Rubery (1978) used Braverman as a starting point, but introduced material drawn from dual labour
market theory and radical economics to develop a theory of labour market segmentation. In her view,
labour markets are structured not just by the actions of capitalists, but by the ability of workers “to
maintain, develop, extend and reshape their organisation and bargaining power” (1978, 34). A
consequence is the development of a range of non-competing labour markets, an idea which seems
closer to the Weberian concept of closure – “the process by which social collectivities seek to
maximize rewards by restricting access to resources and opportunities to a limited circle of eligibles”
(Parkin 1979, 44) – than to the Marxist notion of the reserve army of labour found in Braverman.
Littler, Rubery and others like them can be seen as having entered into a dialogue with Marxist
writers. Paul Edwards (1986), in another major synthesis of labour process theory, made substantial
use of Marxist concepts, but went to considerable lengths to distance his work from Marxism. Noting
a broad theoretical similarity between Marxists and radical non-Marxists in the use of such terms as
exploitation, contradiction, and the centrality of workplace struggle, Edwards terms his approach
“materialist” but not Marxist (1986, 88). A key difference, in his view, is that “Marxism must propose
some logic of social development such that exploitation will be transcended, whereas materialism
makes no such claim” (1986, 89). While a position such as Edwards’s is sympathetic towards workers,
there is no expectation that class conflict will necessarily lead to social transformation or even that the
common class situation of labour will result in shared subjective interests. A similar view to that of
Edwards is adopted by Thompson (1990, 102), one of the relatively few major radical writers who
maintained an ongoing involvement in labour process analysis from the early 1980s to the present.
More recently, Rowlinson and Hassard (1994) have argued that Braverman, by adopting the
economics of Baran and Sweezy (1966), departed considerably from orthodox Marxism. According to
Rowlinson and Hassard, the labour process theorists abandon such central Marxist tenets as the labour
theory of value and the law of the tendency of the rate of profit to fall, concentrating instead on
struggles over relations of dominance and subordination. Thus “the connection with Marxian political
economy is largely severed, and it becomes difficult to distinguish labour process theory from radical
organisation theory” (1994, 70).
Despite the similarities between Marxist and non-Marxist “second wave” labour process analysis, the
rejection of Marxism by most writers by the mid 1980s constitutes the first stage of the dissolution of a
cohesive labour process framework. Indeed, given differences among Braverman and the Marxist
4
second wave theorists, it is arguable that despite a number of shared ideas, a coherent labour process
theory may never have existed at all.
The post-structuralist or “Foucauldian turn” subsequently introduced a much deeper theoretical rift.
The work of Knights and Willmott in particular (Knights 1990; Willmott 1990; Knights and
Vurdubakis 1994; Knights and Willmott 1989) has been very influential, especially their theorizing of
subjectivity and resistance. They argue that both Marxist labour process theorists and their non-
Marxist critics are guilty of dualism. One pole of this dualism revolves around the distinction between
agency/structure or voluntarism/determinism in which subjectivity is tacitly conceptualized as “that
creative autonomy or personal space not yet captured by political economy” (Knights and Willmott
1989, 549). The second dualistic element is said to be an essentialism in the form of an assumption
that there is an “inner essence” which is violated in the capitalist labour process ” (552). Instead,
Knights and Willmott (1989, 554) argue that subjectivity and power are mutually constitutive, such
that “subjectivity is understood as a product of disciplinary mechanisms, techniques of surveillance
and power-knowledge strategies: human freedom is constituted through their mediation of
subjectivity”.
In the course of a critical discussion of post-structuralist theory, Thompson (1993, 202) suggests that
when applied to the labour process, it entails a “retreat from engagement”, which might be seen as a
diversion of labour process theory away from its original radical direction. Knights and Vurdubakis
(1994) deny this accusation, as does Townley (1994) in her Foucauldian critique of human resource
management. More recently, Thompson and Ackroyd (1995) suggest that, although post-structuralist
analysis is predicated on the view that power inherently gives rise to resistance, worker resistance has
been theoretically neglected and empirically invisible in post-structuralist writing. Ironically,
according to Thompson and Ackroyd, this replicates one of the central problems identified by early
critics of Braverman.
The infusion of Foucauldian ideas has rekindled the labour process debate along new lines, with the
opponents much further apart than during the earlier period. Indeed, there is less a debate than a
gaping chasm across which dismissive polemics are occasionally hurled. It seems likely that the
injection of post-structuralism into labour process analysis will result in further dissolution rather than
a new synthesis.
A second trend in the labour process literature theory was fragmentation. As mentioned earlier, Littler
(1990) identified three key themes in labour process analysis: deskilling, management strategy and
labour markets. While early contributions such as Littler (1982) attempted to formulate a synthesis,
research in each strand soon developed a dynamic of its own. The labour process literature quickly
evolved into disconnected debates over the meaning of skill and whether or not deskilling was
occurring, or whether multiple control strategies could be used.
Later, discussions of strategy receded in the labour process literature. Critics such as Storey (1985)
noted that the strategy literature was too generalized. First, it was argued that most enterprises do not
use one particular strategy, but a range of strategies simultaneously. Second, the early labour process
literature portrayed management as more conscious and rational than they typically are in dealing with
labour. Allied to this is a third point, that labour control is usually less important to employers than
early labour process theory suggested. It is ironic that not long after early labour process theory was
busily elevating labour control to the top of management’s agenda, the new breed of HRM writers
were lamenting the failure of management to take the personnel function sufficiently seriously! Some
contributors to the labour process debates continued to be interested in management strategy, but only
Friedman (1990) sought to incorporate the criticisms into a more sophisticated version of labour
process theory. Paul Edwards (1987), for example, examined the prevalence of “macho management”
in Britain, while Storey (1992) has made a major contribution to the analysis of human resource
management. Both Edwards and Storey’s recent work deals with strategy, but neither uses a labour
process perspective.
5
In addition to a new epistemological approach, the entry of the Foucauldians to the field in the late
1980s shifted attention towards subjectivity, an issue raised earlier by Burawoy (1979). Their work
had little overlap with the empirical concerns of most earlier labour process writers.
After Edwards (1986) there was no attempt to develop a synthesis. Thompson (1990) sought to
redevelop a core theory, but by this stage the Foucauldian critique had emerged and Thompson has
sought to criticise rather than incorporate their work. Thus the labour process literature proceeded by
developing a number of discrete debates, each of which was worthwhile, but there was little attempt to
maintain a theoretical integration between the broad issues.
Third, many of the insights of labour process theory have been assimilated by mainstream researchers,
particular in industrial relations in the UK. It is instructive to note, for example, that Dunn (1990)
refers in passing to Paul Edwards as an industrial relations “mainstreamer”. This is the same Paul
Edwards whose theoretical work is based on the idea of “a basic conflict of interest between capital
and labour … rendered in the notion of a structured antagonism” (1986, 77). Edwards himself (1995,
44), writing about industrial relations in the UK, later noted that
The [mainstream] pluralists accepted some of the key points of radical analysis, in
particular as expressed through renewed attention to the labour process. The
indeterminacy of the labour contract … became a standard theme in teaching in the early
1980s, with works like those of Richard Edwards (1979) and Andrew Friedman (1977)
being widely studied.
This understanding would no doubt be shared by many mainstream industrial relations writers in the
UK – and indeed in Australia as well, although the influence of labour process analysis has been
minimal in the United States.
The failure of labour process theory to make much headway in the US is interesting, and difficult to
explain except in terms of the more conservative nature of American social science in comparison
with the UK and Australia. The contours of these differences are well beyond the scope of this paper.
Most British and Australian industrial relations academics, for example, would have some familiarity
with labour process analysis or at least its subject matter, but Kaufman’s (1993) history of academic
industrial relations in the US fails to mention it at all. Similarly, standard American industrial
sociology textbooks such as Hall (1994) and Hodson and Sullivan (1995) mention the key writers in
the labour process literature only in passing, while British texts such as Grint (1991), Thompson and
McHugh (1995) and Watson (1995) devote considerable attention to the approach.
If labour process analysis made little impact in the US, many of the insights of first and second wave
labour process theory are now everyday fare amongst the academic mainstream in the UK and
Australia. While many British and Australian researchers would feel uncomfortable with the Marxist
sounding terminology, arguments over skill, control and labour markets that draw on labour process
concepts would hardly be considered exotic. Shorn of its Marxist and radical Weberian assumptions, it
was assimilated into the mainstream and lost much of its distinctiveness.
Similarly, some of the iterations of labour process theory have been assimilated by other schools of
thought, such as feminism. Although Braverman addressed the situation of female workers, a
fundamental problem with Marxist class categories is that they are gender blind. Work on gender
issues has been a strong feature of the labour process literature from an early stage (see West (1990)
for a review). In particular, feminists have done important work on both labour markets and the social
construction of skill. However, introducing concepts developed in feminist discourse took labour
process theory further from its Marxist origins. Indeed, as West (1990, 246) argues, many feminist
issues fit poor ly within Marxist categories. Furthermore, the centrality of domestic labour to feminist
analysis stands in an uneasy relationship with the labour process focus on paid employment. In
Australia, labour process theory has informed some important feminist historical research into the
development of work, trade unionism and the domestic division of labour (Bennett 1984; Frances
6
1993; Reiger 1985), as well as writing on contemporary industrial relations and sociological issues
(Probert 1989; Williams 1988).
Finally, it could be argued that a number of researchers in the labour process tradition have been
coopted to less radical approaches. There clearly has been a general decline in the popularity of radical
thought in universities in anglophone countries since the halcyon days of academic Marxism in the
1970s. For some writers, there doubtless would have been a genuine intellectual disenchantment with
radical theory and an attraction to other schools of thought. The shift away from labour process theory
would be all the easier because of its weak link with Marxist economics (Rowlinson and Hassard
1994) and its affinity with Weberian perspectives which easily merge with a reformist research
agenda. Furthermore, a number of academics who began their careers as young, radical political
economists or sociologists now occupy senior positions in schools of management or business. They
deal readily with business, government and mainstream funding institutions. While these scholars have
generally retained a critical edge to their published work, and can by no means be considered to have
joined the ranks of some former radicals who became neo-conservatives, their criticisms now come
from within the political mainstream, and at a considerable distance theoretically from early labour
process perspectives. Without knowing the personal histories of those involved, it would be futile to
speculate on the reasons for their intellectual shifts. Certainly, as Rowlinson and Hassard (1994, 66)
argue, working in a business school has no inherent bearing on one’s theoretical perspective, though in
most cases business school radicals will find few intellectual fellow travellers in nearby offices. The
point remains that the insight and energy of the early labour process theorists who abandoned the
approach has not been replaced, and the redirection of their interests has clearly weakened the debates.
My argument is that labour process theory began to change at an early stage, such that it is
inappropriate to speak of a unified “perspective ” at least from the time that Rubery (1978) and Littler’s
(1982) work appeared. Thompson (1990) seeks to salvage a common core from the “wreckage. To
some extent the appearance of common ground was encouraged in the early labour process debates by
the radicalism of most of the participants, which glossed over their differences. But there are a range
of radical perspectives, as indeed there are a variety of perspectives within Marxism itself, and the
introduction of non-Marxist frameworks made it unlikely that common ground would be reestablished.
The growth of Foucauldian ideas confirmed what was already evident in hindsight.
Is labour process analysis still useful? I believe that it is, bearing in mind that no one theory wears the
labour process mantle. Personally, I continue to find Littler’s (1982) three level framework of the
employment relationship, the structure of control and job design a fruitful model for analysing
relations at work. Similarly Burawoy’s (1985) discussion of the politics of production, both in terms of
the micro-politics of the workplace and the role of the state in work relations have helped me make
sense of work organizations. Rubery’s (1978) early work on labour markets became an important
foundation of subsequent labour market research. While few would now agree that capitalism contains
an inherent dynamic of deskilling, labour process analysis keeps me wary of the enthusiasms of post-
Fordist and postmodern writers concerning employee empowerment and skill upgrading. I remain
sceptical of those for whom increasing productivity has taken theoretical priority over reducing
inequality. And so on.
Judging from the articles in the past few volumes of a journal like Work, Employment & Society, and
even the more mainstream Work and Occupations, many researchers seem to share the view that
labour process concepts are still worthwhile, including those found in the early works of Braverman
and the second wave writers. While labour process analysis has waned with the general waning of
radicalism in universities and elsewhere, it has nevertheless contributed a leavening of concepts which
question the understandings of managerial ideologies. It is surely not a coincidence that so many
academics in Britain and Australia, where labour process theory has wide recognition, are interested in
the ways in which human resource management practices constitute a new form of control, whereas in
the United States, researchers seem far more concerned with whether HRM is positively associated
with higher levels of productivity.
7
I do not believe, however, that there is now a coherent labour process perspective, and an argument
can be made that if one ever existed, it was fleeting, for the reasons outlined above. Most significantly,
labour process analysis suffered the proliferation and subsequent decline of radical scholarship more
generally, though it retains a small but hardy following and a wider influence within mainstream
research.
With the entry of post-structuralists to labour process analysis, the prospect of a cohesive approach is
less likely than ever. In addition to the difficulties Foucauldians have agreeing amongst themselves, I
am unaware of any suggestion that there might be a synthesis between post-structuralism and the more
traditional radicalism of writers like Thompson. The early theoretical debates on the labour process
were marked by both disagreement as well as a search for common ground, but more recent debates
seem to consist mostly of drawing lines in the sand. Furthermore, while post-structuralist theory has
enjoyed a degree of popularity in fields like organisational studies, it has remained marginal in other
areas – notably industrial relations and industrial sociology – which have been heavily influenced by
early labour process theory. Quite apart from any intellectual merits the post-structuralist approach
might have, the difficulty – dare I say inability – that many of those working in this tradition have
writing clear English makes it hard to see post-structuralism attracting the wider interest which might
lead to a revitalisation of the labour process approach.
Until such time as there is a rekindling of radical perspectives more generally, the main contribution of
labour process theory has probably already been made. The labour process debates played a crucial
role in refocusing the interest of mainstream industrial relations and industrial sociology on a range of
management issues using a critical perspective, and away from the previous limited focus on workers,
unions and productivity. At least in Australian and Great Britain, it is hard to imagine non-managerial
research in the broad areas of work and employment relations which is not influenced by labour
process insights.
8
References
Baran, Paul and Paul Sweezy (1966), Monopoly Capital, New York, Monthly Review Press
Bennett, Laura (1984) `The Construction of Skill: Craft Unions, Women Workers and the Conciliation
and Arbitration System’, Law in Context, 2, 118-32
Braverman, Harry (1974) Labor and Monopoly Capital, New York Monthly Review Press
Brown, Richard (1992) Understanding Industrial Organisations: Theoretical Perspectives in Industrial
Sociology, London, Routledge
Burawoy, Michael (1979) Manufacturing Consent: Changes in the Labor Process under Monopoly
Capitalism, Chicago, University of Chicago Press
Burawoy, Michael (1985) The Politics of Production, London, Verso
Deacon, Desley (1985) `Taylorism in the Home: the Medical Profession, the Infant Welfare
Movement and the Deskilling of Women’ Australian and New Zeala nd Journal of Sociology, 21,2,
161-73
Edwards, Paul (1986) Conflict at Work, Oxford, Blackwell
Edwards, Paul (1987) Managing the Factory, Oxford, Blackwell
Edwards, Paul (1995) `From Industrial Relations to the Employment Relationship: The Development
of Research in Britain’, Relations Industrielles, 50,1, 39-63
Edwards, Richard (1979) Contested Terrain: The Transformation of the Workplace in the Twentieth
Century, London, Heinemann
Edwards, Richards (1993) Rights at Work: Employment Relations in the Post-Union Era, Washington,
DC, Brookings Institution
Elger, Tony and Chris Smith (eds) (1994) Global Japanization?, London, Routledge
Frances, Raelene (1993) The Politics of Work: Gender and Labour in Victoria, 1880-1939,
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press
Friedman, Andrew (1977) Industry & Labour: Class Struggle at Work and Monopoly Capitalism,
London, Macmillan
Friedman, Andrew (1990) `Managerial Strategies, Activities, Techniques and Technology: Towards a
Complex Theory of the Labour Process’, in D Knights and H Willmott (eds) Labour Process Theory,
London, Macmillan
Grint, Keith (1991) The Sociology of Work, Cambridge, Polity Press
Hall, Richard (1994) The Sociology of Work, Thousand Oaks, Pine Forge Press
Hodson, Randy and Teresa Sullivan (1995) The Social Organization of Work (2nd ed), Belmont,
Wadsworth
9
Jermier, John, David Knights and Walter Nord (eds) (1994) Resistance and Power in Organizations,
London, Routledge
Kaufman, Bruce (1993) The Origins & Evolution of the Field of Industrial Relations in the United
States, Ithaca, Cornell University Press
Knights, David (1990) `Subjectivity, Power and the Labor Process’, in D Knights and H Willmott
(eds) Labour Process Theory, London, Macmillan
Knights, David and Theo Vurdubakis (1994) `Foucault, Power and All That’, in J Jermier, D Knights
and W Nord (eds) Resistance & Power in Organizations, London, Routledge
Knights, David and Hugh Willmott (eds) (1986) Gender and the Labour Process, Aldershot, Gower
Knights, David and Hugh Willmott (eds) (1988) New Technology and the Labour Process, London,
Macmillan
Knights, David and Hugh Willmott (1989) `Power and Subjectivity at Work: From Degradation to
Subjugation in the Labour Process’, Sociology, 23,4, 535-58
Knights, David and Hugh Willmott (1990) `Introduction’, in D Knights and H Willmott (eds) Labour
Process Theory, London, Macmillan
Knights, David, Hugh Willmott and David Collinson (eds) (1988) Job Redesign, Aldershot, Gower
Littler, Craig (1982) The Development of the Labour Process in Capitalist Societies, London,
Heinemann
Littler, Craig (1990) `The Labour Process Debate: A Theoretical Review 1974-1988’, in D Knights
and H Willmott (eds) Labour Process Theory, London, Macmillan
Littler, Craig and Graeme Salaman (1982) `Bravermania and Beyond: Recent Theories of the Labour
Process’, Sociology, 16,2, 251-69
Parkin, Frank (1979) Marxism and Class Theory: A Bourgeois Critique, London, Tavistock
Probert, Belinda (1989) Working Life, Melbourne, McPhee Gribble
Reiger, Kerreen (1985) The Disenchantment of the Home: Modernizing the Australian Family 1880-
1940, Melbourne, Oxford University Press
Rowlinson, Michael and John Hassard (1994) `Economics, Politics and Labour Process Theory’,
Capital & Class, 53, 65-97
Rubery, Jill (1978) `Structured Labour Markets, Worker Organisation and Low Pay’, Cambridge
Journal of Economics, 2, 17-36
Smith, Chris, David Knights and Hugh Willmott (eds) (1991) White-Collar Work: The Non-Manual
Labour Process, London, Macmillan
Storey, John (1983) Managerial Prerogative and the Question of Control, London, Routledge & Kegan
Paul
Storey, John (1985) `The Means of Management Control’, Sociology, 19,2, 193-211
10
Storey, John (1992) Developments in the Management of Human Resources, Oxford, Blackwell
Sturdy, Andrew, David Knights and Hugh Willmott (eds) (1992) Skill & Consent: Contemporary
Studies in the Labour Process, London, Routledge
Thompson, Paul (1983), The Nature of Work, London, Macmillan (also 1989, 2nd edition)
Thompson, Paul (1990), `Crawling from the Wreckage: The Labour Process and the Politics of
Production’, in D Knights and H Willmott (eds) Labour Process Theory, London, Macmillan
Thompson, Paul (1993) `Postmodernism: Fatal Distraction’, in J Hassard and M Parker (eds)
Postmodernism and Orgnizations, London, Sage
Thompson, Paul and Stephen Ackroyd (1995) `All Quiet on the Workplace Front? A Critique of
Recent Trends in British Industrial Sociology, Sociology, 29,4, 615-33
Thompson, Paul and David McHugh (1995) Work Organisations (2nd ed), London, Macmillan
Townley, Barbara (1994) Reframing Human Resource Management: Power, Ethics and the Subject,
London, Sage
Watson, Tony (1995) Sociology, Work and Industry (3rd ed), London, Routledge
West, Jackie (1990) `Gender and the Labour Process: A Reassessment’, in D Knights and H Willmott
(eds) Labour Process Theory, London, Macmillan
Williams, Claire (1988) Blue, White and Pink Collar Workers in Australia, Sydney, Allen & Unwin
Willmott, Hugh (1990) `Subjectivity and the Dialectics of Praxis: Opening up the Core of Labour
Process Analysis’, in D Knights and H Willmott (eds) Labour Process Theory, London, Macmillan

Read Full Post »

Organisation Theory 1

List of authors and its contribution – Organisation Theory

Hannan, Freeman: Organizational Ecology uses a biological analogy and statistical analysis to try and understand the conditions under which organizations emerge, grow, and die. (birth, adolescence, maturity, death/decline)

McKelvey and Aldrich: 1. Variation, 2. Selection, 3. Retention (Preserved, duplicated, reproduced), 4. Struggle.

Nelson and Winter: Lock in and path dependency. Evolutionary economics. Observes that as a dominant design emerges within any industry, barriers to entry begin to rise as the technological and capital needed for competitive production grow. Additional learning becomes cumulative (result: incumbent firms have an advantage relative to the potential new entrant.) Structural inertia. In economic development, it is said (initially by Paul David in 1985) that a standard which is first-to-market can become entrenched (like the QWERTY layout in typewriters still used in computer keyboards). He called this “path dependence”, and argued that inferior standards can persist simply because of the legacy they have built up. The case against QWERTY has been criticized (e.g. by The Fable of the Keys), but standards are clearly very important in modern economies, and the significance of path dependence in determining how they form is the subject of economic debate.

Joseph Schumpeter:: Competitive destroying advantage. “how organizations can balance the tension between exploitation and exploration”, evolutionary econs = chance of survival = all about innovation. Competition between firms drives them towards innovation. Schumpeter describes the process of industrial transformation that accompanies radical innovation. In Schumpeter‘s vision of capitalism, innovative entry by entrepreneurs was the force that sustained long-term economic growth, even as it destroyed the value of established companies that enjoyed some degree of monopoly power.

Douglass North – Institutions provide the incentive structure of the economy.

Contingency theory – the best way to organize depends on the nature of the environment to which the organization must relate.

Thomas Kuhn;:

As a paradigm is stretched to its limits, anomalies — failures of the current paradigm to take into account observed phenomena — accumulate. In any community of scientists, Kuhn states, there are some individuals who are bolder than most. These scientists, judging that a crisis exists, embark on what Thomas Kuhn calls revolutionary science, exploring alternatives to long-held, obvious-seeming assumptions. Occasionally this generates a rival to the established framework of thought. There typically follows a period in which there are adherents of both paradigms. In time, if the challenging paradigm is solidified and unified, it will replace the old paradigm, and a paradigm shift will have occurred.

List of paradigm shifts in science

  • 1930s: The development of Quantum mechanics, which redefined classical mechanics.
  • 1930s or 1940s: The acceptance of Plate tectonics as the explanation for large-scale geologic changes.
  • Mid to late 20th Century: The movement, known as the Cognitive revolution, away from Behaviourist approaches to psychological study and the acceptance of cognition as central to studying human behaviour.

Burrell, G., & Morgan, G

The matrix is based on four main debates in sociology:

  • * is reality given or a product of the mind?
  • * must one experience something to understand it?
  • * do humans have “free will”, or are they determined by their environment?
  • * is understanding best achieved through the scientific method or through direct experience?

The authors coalesce these debates into two fundamental issues that form the axes of the 2×2 matrix:

  • * social theories emphasizing regulation and stability vs those emphasizing radical change
  • * subjective (individualistic) theories vs objective (structural) theories

Functionalist Paradigm (objective-regulation) This has been the primary paradigm for organizational study. It assumes rational human action and believes one can understand organizational behavior through hypothesis testing. 1. provided foundation for most modern theory and research on the subject of organization. 2. provided the basis for an organisation’s progress and development of a formal organization. 3. provided regularities and relationships so that they can predict and control (certainty)

Interpretive Paradigm (subjective-regulation) This paradigm “seeks to explain the stability of behavior from the individual’s viewpoint”. Researchers in this paradigm try to observe “on-going processes” to better understand individual behavior and the “spiritual nature of the world”. 1. provides an impetus for innovation. 2. provides an importance of understanding organization as a cultural phenomenon rich in contextually based system of meaning. 3. socially constructed web of symbolic relationships that are continually negotiated, affirmed and changed.

Radical Humanist Paradigm (subjective-radical change) Theorists in this paradigm are mainly concerned with releasing social constraints that limit human potential. They see the current dominant ideologies as separating people from their “true selves”. They use this paradigm to justify desire for revolutionary change. It’s largely anti-organization in scope. 1. provides a search for the ideological traps and blinders that lead human beings to feel powerless in dealing with the contingencies of their everyday world. 2. draws attention to the power dimensions (restoring power to people). 3. provides highlight to the unconscious significance of organization (shaping society) 4. oganisations exist to develop full potential of people.

Radical Structuralist Paradigm (objective-radical change) Based on this paradigm, theorists see inherent structural conflicts within society that generate constant change through political and economic crises. This has been the fundamental paradigm of Marx, Engles, and Lenin. 1. provides a distinctive understanding of organizations in crisis.

Alvesson/Willmott :: the purpose of the project is to show how Critical Theory can provide both a penetrating critique of, particularly, management practice as a reflection of a certain type of management theory, and to point a way forward out of the dysfunctions of the current dominant understanding of management.

Jeffrey Pfeffer – unifying paradigm

Hatch – illuminate the same phenomenon from different point of view.

Anthony Giddens – Structuration theory (simultaneously consideration)

Braverman – the need to understand control and resistance of workers.

Andrew Friedman terms “responsible autonomy” and “direct control” (see his book INDUSTRY AND LABOR, London: Macmillan, 1977). In the former, workers are given some freedom to make decision on their own but are then held responsible for their actions by management. The latter follows the Taylorist model, simplifying the job so that it can be more tightly controlled by management.

Edwards “bureaucratic control” systems typify very large prosperous firms that have the financial latitude to treat labor as a fixed, stable cost, rather than firms that must continually struggle to increase productivity and pump profits. Bureaucratic control, in sum, is more likely to exist in profitable firms with huge market shares.

Burawoy – Rather than ask the traditional Marxist question of “Why do workers work at all (given their interests are opposite those of capitalists)?”, Burawoy wonders why workers work as hard as they do (knowing their efforts merely make more money for the company owners). Burawoy notes that workers today actually embrace the fundamentals of capitalism that constrain them.

“Manufacturing Consent” He concludes that management really controls workers by giving labor the “illusion of choice” in a highly restrictive environment. Worker participation in this co-optation creates consent and minimizes the potential of class consciousness and labor-management conflict while maximizing productivity.

1. Piece-rate Pay System

In the machine shop, the piece-rate system created the illusion of labor as a game. Workers competed with each other to “make out” and surpass their expected production quotas. Over time the job satisfaction came from mastering the intricate and often devious strategies to “make out” under various production conditions. Those more skillful in “playing all the angles” garnered the most respect and prestige.

The “making out” game separated the worker’s interests and obscured the fact that management was gaining productivity with only minor increases in wages. The act of playing the game generated consent for its rules while providing a challenging diversion to the general boredom of repetitive labor (Burawoy, 1979).

2. Internal Labor Market

Increasing job mobility within the company allowed management to reduce conflict and increase the illusion that workers had choice. Potential labor conflicts could be avoided by separating workers.

3. Collective Bargaining

Burawoy also concluded that the collective bargaining between unions and management was also another “game” that gave labor the illusion of participation and choice.

Therefore, instead of alienating workers, modern capitalism has succeeded in co-opting workers into embracing capitalism as the preferred ideology (despite the fundamental differences between capital and labor). While Burawoy contends that capitalism is merely the current phase in the evolution of society, he is pessimistic that capitalism will decline in the near future (Burawoy, 1979).

Sennet – “The corrosion of character” the personal consequences of work in the new capitalism: how we relate to work at subjective end, how we control ourselves at work, rather than being controlled in the way that braverman stressed. (talking about janitor, predicted income, hardworking, compared with his son, earns alot and unpredicted future of incomes.

Jurgen Habermas – In Habermas’s epistemology, critical knowledge was conceptualized as knowledge that enabled human beings to emancipate themselves from forms of domination through self-reflection and took psychoanalysis as the paradigm of critical knowledge. This expanded considerably the scope of what counted as critical theory within the social sciences, which would include such approaches as world systems theory, feminist theory, postcolonial theory, critical race theory, performance studies, transversal poetics, queer theory, social ecology, the theory of communicative action (Jürgen Habermas), structuration theory, and neo-Marxian theory. – the concept of public sphere. Critical Theory:: Jurgen Habermas:: adopted ideas from Marxism, The elites benefit from maintaining status quo. When a manager disallows debate, workers become powerless. Therefore, theorists need to challenge that which is taken for granted.

Alvesson, Willmott On the Idea of Emancipation in Management and Organization Studies -The article reconceptualizes the meaning of emancipation in management and organization studies and develops an approach that (a) takes into account recent criticism of its “totalizing” tendencies raised by poststructuralists and (b) makes it more sensitive to the particularities of-and thereby more relevant for-management studies. Critical Theory can provide both a penetrating critique of, particularly, management practice as a reflection of a certain type of management theory, and to point a way forward out of the dysfunctions of the current dominant understanding of management.

Michel Foucault – Societies have shifted from exercising control through external coercion to persuading people that it is in their interest and to obey the rules. Makes the person become his own supervisor. Failure to conform = anxious (inadequate feeling) Foucauldian approach: micro understanding, detailed ways in which people’s behaviour and attitudes are constructed through systems of knowledge and discursive practices. Although physical control is important, surveillance is more important, especially over what we cannot physically control – our mind. Thus society has shifted from exercising control through external coercion to persuading people that it is in their own interests to obey. Disobedience is a sign of personal failure or a form of pathology (illness!). conformity arises from the fear of being perceived as being different from the norm. (surveillance is deemed more important than punishment. Knowing that you are being watched or being closely monitored enforces conformity more effectively because it internalizes the work ethic and makes a person to become his own supervisor. (failure to conform doesn’t lead directly to punishment, instead the individual feels anxious and inadequate. (voluntarily)

Rose – “governing the soul” how to get commitment, loyalty of the employee becomes very important.

4 different paradigms:

Radical Structuralist::

Labour Process Theory emphasizes the way in which management exercises forms of external control and discipline through wage systems, monitoring of performance systems and punishment systems.

Read Full Post »

small discovery..

today i found out that the soundtrack embedded in the game files, known as a .DAT extension file, is playable through the use of windows media classic player.. it’s a small discovery but i think i won’t realise it if i didn’t tinker the thing in the first place… (Ciborra’s Bricolage ftw..) and uh today i’m cutting small pieces of soundtrack of Medieval War 2, and convert them to .mp3. i loved the OST alot and i think it’s damn nice soundtrack, originally composed by Jeff van Dyck. ❤ ❤

since i’ve forgotten to bring back my connection HP-laptop cable, now i won’t be able to upload it into my hp.. i think i need to wait another few weeks to get it back.. i left it at vivo outlet… dang.. dang.. shit..

Read Full Post »